Frequently Asked Questions (roughly in order of when they come up in the semester):

1) "I'm Xth on the waitlist.  Can you do anything?  Will I get in?"
    No, unfortunately, I have been taken out of the loop.  I don't know whether you will get in or not--if you are 1st or 2nd for a recitation with an unpopular time (e.g. 8 am on Friday), you are very likely to get in.  The control is by recitation, not by the overall class, so there are many people who are 1st and 2nd waitlisted.  We have a very difficult registration system; there are in principle better systems, but so many students are involved that any system seems beset with problems.

2) "When is the first midterm going to be?  I have to be out of town on for the days of X to Y."
    The first midterm will be very close to half-way through the semester.  About a week and a half before that time, I will offer several possible dates to the class...we will vote on those dates, dropping less popular dates, until there is a winner.  In this way, we can get the best chance of getting the "socially-optimal test date."  However, this approach does not, as an example of a voting problem for "public goods," reflect the "intensity of want."  That is, if one date wins with a 51% to 49% of the vote, it is possible that the "wrong" date might have been selected, because those who don't get their date might possibly "care" more than those who do.  If the vote spread is very large (it often is), it is likely that we will pick the best date, though one cannot ever be totally certain.

3) "What is my assignment this week?"
    I have little in the way of formal assignments...your recitation instructors are likely to be giving you something much more specific than you will ever get from me.  It is generally desirable to be reading a bit ahead of where I am in class.  In the beginning few lectures, you might feel somewhat adrift--just read the introductory material (the things prior to Demand and Supply) in the book and in the handouts; you will be fine.  As the course proceeds, it will become clearer and clearer where we are...the syllabus keys the organization to the book chapters and the handouts are also quite similar to the book chapters.  If you are really confused, e-mail me and I'll tell you where you should be on both the reading of the book and the handouts.

4) "Is there an Economics Club, that has social activities?"
    Yes, in fact, there are generally several activities in planning stages or underway...if you are enjoying the class, why not drop in on those two events and check it out!

5) "What would be an example of a Kaldor to Pareto efficient projects conversion?"
    The inspection/maintenance system of car auto exhaust might be an example.  It hurts the poor more than the rich, but probably has net benefits to society as a whole.  If enough other money were given to the poor (e.g. through an income tax reduction), you could make them better off, too.  That is, if there are dollar B > C overall for the program, then you can take away some of the dollar benefits from those who receive them and give those dollars to those who pay the costs and have something left over.
    For example, suppose the "winners" benefit $800 while those paying the costs ("losers") pay $600 and there are 200 people in our society, one hundred each of winners and losers.  The losers, without compensation, lose $6 each, while the winners win $8 each, so the project has more total benefits than costs (Kaldor Efficient).  But, we can't know whether it makes people better off collectively because we don't know how much each group values a dollar.  If, however, the winners pay $700 to the losers, everybody is better off with the policy (each person now has a net benefit of $1, from the $600 cost investment)--it is converted, by the dollar transfers, from being Kaldor Efficient to being Pareto Efficient.

6) "What is the difference between supply and quantity?  I thought I was clear on the matter but in class today I realized I was not clear when you related an example with coffee.  The example was when both curves shifted:  If coffee was proven healthy, yet there was a frost in Columbia what would happen?  If demand for coffee went up, and supply went down the price would go up but we do not know what would happen to the quantity.  Now if supply went down, wouldn't quantity go down too?"
    Your confusion stems from the slopes of the curves in this case...you are subconsciously thinking of a vertical supply curve for coffee that is shifting leftward (somewhat understandable in the case of a frost that reduces the coffee crop).  But, at higher prices there will be more coffee taken from inventories from other years, more care will be given to the beans that survive the frost and so on...so there is an upward-slope to the supply curve--hence if the demand increases enough, there might be more or less coffee supplied--even though the frost killed a lot of this year's crop.  [Green coffee beans store for a long time--only after they are, in varying amounts, roasted are they more "fragile"].
    You raise a good question, though, which suggests that you are actively working to figure the material out--you'll do fine!  To better see what YOU were thinking, draw the coffee market with the vertical supply curve shifting leftward due to the frost.  Then quantity does unambiguously fall, and price just rises by more (due to the demand increase) than it would due to the supply reduction alone.  This case is confusing because people tend to think of perishable crops (e.g. lettuce) that are supplied in fairly vertical amounts that just vary according to conditions that year.  To avoid such confusions, this is why I recommend that you just assume the "normal" shaped D (downward sloping) and S (upward sloping) curves!

7) "The first midterm is now over...how do I know how I did?"
    I have posted (by the last six digits of your student ID number) your scores outside my office on the wall (NW corner, 2nd floor of the Economics Bldg).  Also written on that posting is how many points to add to your score.  How many points get added depends on the difficulty of the exam, and varies from exam to exam...it is generally a "good thing" if the test is more difficult, since it is easier for more people who do well on a difficult exam to get out of the final (missing a few on a hard exam allows people to go well over 100 points, while an easy exam is limited to that number, and a careless answer puts you at 96 or so).  See syllabus for further information on the elaborate grading system.

8) "Where are the exam and correct answers posted?"
    Usually I allow students to keep their exams so that they can know how they answered each question (assuming that they indicated on their test what they answered, prior to transferring it to the scantron).  I post the correct answers on the web immediately after the exams are completed.  It will be useful to be sure you understand why each correct answer is correct and why none of the other possible answers are correct; this will enable you to do better on the final.  Good luck!

9) "When will the second midterm take place?"
    It will be approximately in the second to last week of the course...this forces those who are destined to get out of the final to learn a much higher percentage of the material.

10)"Hi....I've been reviewing past exams and have some questions (below).  Yikes, some of the questions are
confusing.  Are you going to make this one exceptionally hard?"
     All tests seem hard to some people and easy to others!  :)

"1.  Spring '98 exam:  #13.  Suppose a monopolist sells 4 units of output at a price of $5 but must lower price to $4 to sell 5 units.  Suppose that monopolist is price discriminator and purchasers of the first 4 units are unaware of the price cut necessary to sell the additional unit.  What is the marginal revenue form selling the 5th unit and would the profit-maximizing monopolist do this?  The answer is $4 and price discriminator should lower the price and sell one more unit only if the MC of producing one more unit is less than $4.  I don't understand why it's $4???"
     Any producer will would sell something as long as the marginal benefit of doing that is greater than or equal to the marginal cost of doing that (because they want to make themselves as well off as possible).  The marginal benefit for the price discriminator is $4 (since she doesn't have to lower the $5 price to those paying $5, in order to sell the extra unit)...this is then compared to the marginal cost of supplying another unit; as long as the marginal cost (all the variable costs that increase when output rises) is less than or equal to $4, the firm will want to produce the unit.

"2.  Also, when you talk about producing being "worthwhile financially" do you always have to include implicit and explicit costs?  Because it seems tobe that producing could not be worthwhile in the short run but in thelong run it could be."
     Actually you have it reversed--in the short run, only variable costs must be covered to stay in business (i.e. the marginal costs are what matter to production decisions and the revenue need only cover the variable costs for the firm to continue producing), while in the long run all costs must be covered.  Yes, it is all costs (explicit and implicit) that matter in the preceding sentence.

"3.  #17 on sum98 exam:  If a monopolist is to be regulated such that the price it charges equal its marginal cost, then:  The total amount produced by the monopolist must increase and society as a whole will be better off.  Why would the monopolist want to produce more because P is not greater than MC?  He would be losing money."
     He might be losing money, unless he is subsidized, if he is a "natural monopoly," but not necessarily otherwise.  The regulation also requires (and this might be unclear) that the monopolist serve all who wish to buy at the regulated price...e.g. they can't restrict how much electricity you use.  We did not talk about regulation of monopolies in class this semester, though, so such questions will not be on the test!  [breathe a sigh of relief!  :) ]

"4.  # 18 sum98:  How can a firm's fixed costs be zero in the long run?  I thought that fixed costs approach zero but never reach zero??"
     The long run is a planning horizon, over which *all* costs are variable.  Once you have actually built whatever number and size of plants you choose, fixed costs exist.  There are always fixed costs "in the real world" of existing plants...that is why we emphasize the short-run so much--we are always in "some" short-run; but in the long-run we can be in a different short-run!  So, returning to your question, when you are planning on what number and size of plants to have (a long-run decision) all of your inputs are variable; there are no "fixed costs"...until you actually build the plants.

"5.  When P is greater than MC the monopoly might not increase output.
Why is this so??"
     Because P could be greater than MC, but marginal revenue (MR)--which is what is relevant to the monopolist, and to be compared to MC--could be *below* MC.